CHINA IN 2020
This sequence involves the following analysis by RHODIUM of the
outlook for China, followed by comments from an analyst and final comments from
me.
China's Outlook – Now and in 2020
by Daniel H. Rosen and Anna Snyder | August 8, 2014
How does economic reform
relate to China’s future economic growth potential? How big a difference does
the difficult undertaking of changing the rules of the marketplace make? The
answer determines whether the risks associated with reform are really worth it.
In our analysis of China’s continuing growth prospects, we put the growth
outlook together in a transparent way, and include scenarios for what happens
if reform falls short. We find that Beijing can hope to deliver 6% annual
growth come 2020 – if it does everything right. Checking with Chinese officials
we find they come to the same conclusion – as do IMF economists in their new
calculations. If reform comes up short, the story is more dire and China can
only look forward to 1-3% GDP growth six years from now. Chinese officials
share that view, and recognize that social stability is tough at those levels,
which is why they are so intent on changing business as usual today.
2020
outlook: Our baseline
expectation is 2020 annual GDP growth of 6%. This assumes China’s ambitious
economic reform program is fully implemented. Our two downturn scenarios – what
the future looks like if reform miscarries – forecast the impact of
hard-landing and crisis on China’s potential growth.
View
from China and view from the Fund: Recent
estimates from China’s leadership and the IMF coalesce around a 6% growth story
for China in 2020. While our estimates vary in a few important ways, the IMF’s
downward revision to China’s growth potential is consistent with our forecast.
Conclusions: China can only count on capital deepening for half of its
2020 growth potential. The other half depends on what economists call total
factor productivity, or TFP. This would be the fruit of urgent, pro-market
reform: adjustment of which sectors get labor and capital, how rapidly
technology advances, and whether wealthier, skilled Chinese keep their assets
at home rather than sending them abroad. The challenge is that this depends on
rapid transformation of financial intermediation and implementation of many
other reforms. Failure to accomplish those tasks would leave GDP growth
somewhere between 1-3% in 2020.
FUNDAMENTAL 2020 OUTLOOK
Our model for China’s
potential growth to 2020 is summarized below (Table 1), with GDP growth rates
year by year and resulting GDP values in constant 2013 dollars – meaning all
values can be understood in today’s purchasing power terms. We explore three
scenarios: our baseline, the highest likelihood soft landing outcome; a hard
landing; and a crisis scenario. We incorporate these projections into a major
forthcoming Asia Society study of China’s reform program to be released this
fall.
We start by considering
projections from the IMF, the World Bank, the Hong Kong Monetary Authority, the
Chinese State Council, and private analysts, and then make adjustments based on
our analysis of reform prospects. This is growth accounting: adding up possible
increases in the factors that go into production (capital, labor, and “improvements”,
including technological upgrading and structural adjustment) to get a more
productive mix. Economists call that final set total factor productivity, or
TFP. 2020 labor force growth in China is zero. Capital stock growth – if all
goes well – could contribute three percentage points to GDP growth, as
investment growth moderates from current rates that have pushed the debt to GDP
ratio to 251% (and rising), according to Stephen Green at Standard Chartered Bank.
Given China’s past performance, it is conceivable that it could generate
another three percentage points of growth from TFP improvement come 2020, if
reform and better enforced regulations dramatically change the industrial mix
(so that private, sunrise industries get resources for a change), for a total
potential of 6%.¹
Our analysis of the
Chinese reform program and implications for China’s GDP outlook has been in the
works since Chinese leadership broadcast an economic reform plan last November,
pledging to give full play to market forces. As our outlook has taken shape, we
continue to benchmark our views against other estimates, including China’s and
the IMF’s, which just updated its long-term projections. In the following
section we walk through these alternative outlooks and relate them to our own.
2020 OUTLOOK: COMPARISON WITH CHINA AND IMF
Hitting this year’s GDP
target of 7.5% is a sensitive political subject which Chinese officials have
little room to discuss. Finance Minister Lou Jiwei and the NDRC tried to move
away from a dogmatic growth number back in April, but in the face of market anxiety
Premier Li re-emphasized the primacy of the target in May and June. But talking
about 2020 is okay. While a few growth-at-all-costs proponents still trumpet
higher numbers, consensus is coalescing around a 6% 2020 outcome, with a 6.5%
average for the five years to come – a major area of agreement with the model
in Table 1. The official Chinese version of this trajectory foresees 20 million
people urbanizing a year through 2020 (higher than we think) and electricity
consumption growth of 6-7% through the decade (also higher than we are
expecting, though we are working to understand why).
More important is a
second area of agreement: what the downside risks to potential growth are and
how low GDP growth would be by 2020 if they eventuated. In the hard landing
scenario, a failure to implement reform sucks the TFP growth out of the
economy, leaving nothing but capital stock growth, resulting in 3% GDP growth.
In a crisis scenario, we imagine capital flight and an investment strike
following the reform² shortfall, depleting capital stock growth and leaving the
Middle Kingdom with barely 1% potential GDP growth – enough, by the NDRC’s
reckoning, to generate jobs for just 1.6 million new entrants of the 10
million-plus who will be looking for work. In our model, the longer Beijing
buys the kind of 7.5% GDP growth it is gunning for today, with the kind of
costly debt creation it is still resorting to, the more likely there will be a
crash in capital stock deepening in the out years. Chinese planners appear to
share this view, understand that the reform imperative is motivating President
Xi and defining China’s long-term growth potential, and agree with the range of
downside outcomes. So we are basically on the same sheet music here, at least
concerning the future headline GDP growth rate potential, which is about as
much as long-term planners can seem to deal with.
Recently, the IMF
released its annual report on the
Chinese economy known as the “Article IV Consultation” – the results of an
annual economic health checkup and summary of vital signs, produced in
consultation with Chinese authorities (meaning a consensus must be reached
between IMF economists and Chinese leadership). The Fund’s read-out on China’s
economic reform agenda and impacts on China’s growth potential is broadly
similar to our own. They expect a 7.4% growth rate in 2014 and project three
medium-term scenarios for Chinese economic growth as well: fast reform, slow
reform (baseline), and no reform.
Our picture differs from
the IMF’s in two key ways. First, our baseline scenario assumes the full range
of reforms laid out in the Third Plenum reform agenda are installed by 2020; by
contrast, the Fund’s baseline assumes steady but slower efforts to implement
reform. Their fast reform scenario closer approximates our baseline. Second,
their reform scenarios model implementation of financial sector, fiscal,
structural, and exchange rate reforms. In addition to those reforms, we
consider the importance of redefining government’s role to focus on public
expenditure priorities instead of industrial policy, pro-competition policies
driving reregulation across sectors, SOE reform, trade and investment reform,
land reform, environmental reform, and welfare reform (policy supports for
labor and human capital). The IMF’s baseline shows growth falling to 6.3% by
2019, whereas ours shows growth slowing to 6.2% in 2019 and 6% by 2020. Slower
growth in the medium-term means faster reform and a lower probability of
crisis. Our balance of payments thinking therefore diverges for similar
reasons; while the IMF’s current account projection hovers around 1% of GDP
through 2023, our current account balance as a percent of GDP falls to zero by
2020. Our projections suggest a modest trade deficit on the horizon, offset by
a positive net income figure – both effects of full-blown reform in the
medium-term, successfully targeting domestic and external imbalances.
Considering the downside
risks to potential growth agreed upon by both Chinese planners and foreign
economists, why are we somewhat more optimistic about the balances? Internally,
we continue to think the evidence of earnestness in reform since the Third
Plenum is more compelling than many observers. On the external side, due to
Rhodium Group’s extensive work on China’s outbound foreign direct investment
imperatives, we are sensitive to just how important a balance will be to China
in the years ahead, despite the indelicate tone Beijing is taking on foreign
economic affairs today. Thus, our baseline assumes the fuller reform required
to sustain cross-border trade and financial flows in the out years. There are
caveats. First, the political challenges to reform implementation are real. The
short-term, debt-driven stimulus propping up growth today is already depressing
future potential, and if it is not reversed soon a hard landing will become the
most likely scenario, increasing the tail risk of crisis, which would shave
world GDP by 2.2% over the next six years and could consume some 20% of global
economic expansion in the year 2020. Second, security fears can trump
universally agreed upon economic logic, and if leaders in Beijing and elsewhere
don’t do a better job tamping down rising nationalism, the obvious benefits of
economic opening could be foolishly sacrificed to guard against self-generated
threats.
DOMESTIC REFORM AND TFP
President Xi Jinping has
smartly observed that China’s market systems must “select the superior and
eliminate the inferior”. Government is not smart enough to dictate how
resources should flow to make that happen. What is superior and what is
inferior is a market decision consumers must make. But the power to do so does
not yet reside with China’s consumers; the state still determines outcomes in
many respects. Over the last year Chinese leaders have started implementing
market reforms, liberalizing finance, and leveling the commercial playing field
to drive competition. It now appears they accept that the efficiency possible
by switching from state allocation to market intermediation is the difference between
3% and 6% 2020 GDP growth rates. To make this switch the state must forego its
monopoly on economic influence in principle and practice. Then high-quality
regulatory institutions and talent pools must be built up. These are Herculean
tasks. The trillion dollar question is whether a regulatory revolution can
happen quickly enough to outrun the tsunami of challenges and enable a 6% 2020
GDP growth outcome.
Notes
¹ Here we don’t factor in a likely significant
upward revision to GDP by the National Bureau of Statistics after its overhaul
of the Chinese national accounts system this year. Neither do we include our
working estimates on nominal GDP level from a separate study we are completing
late this year.
² See our forthcoming study; we define 10 clusters
of policy reform focus, ranging from the financial system to SOE restructuring
to competition policy reform and others. All are partly underway already, but
could stall.
One analysts
reaction:
I've been to so many presentations that show how flawed the
human mind is by automatically trying to find patterns where there are just hints
of a match, and I think that is true of China. It clearly is a case unto
itself.
I also think there is a difference between
watching and worrying, and betting on the outcome.
I think we all have to watch and worry about
everything, since the globe is so much more linked today than it ever
was. We saw that in the rising correlations among the international
markets, and the growing diminishment of the diversification benefits from
international investing. But to bet on the outcome specifically is more
challenging, and I think its so much more difficult not being in the thick of
things. We take transparency in some ways for granted, and while our markets
and economy may be relatively more transparent than China's, it is not clear to
me that they are going to make the same mistakes that we do. They are
sure to make mistakes, as we all are. But making mistakes is just part of
life and learning. Its how you react to those mistakes -- what you do now
to fix/correct them, and what you do differently in the future that determines whether
its been a good or a bad lesson. But I find it really challenging to
believe that a centrally planned economy can be as successful as a relatively
open one can be. It may well be that neither
of our economies are open, and we are a lot
closer than we think ....
AND A CODA FROM ME:
The key to China is what the Rhodium
analysis pinpoints: can the Chinese gov't, the central authority, pull off the
reforms necessary to result in the estimated (guess) 6% growth by 2020?
The challenge is simple but profound.
Central authority = a level of control most less-than-authoritarian regimes
would give their eye teeth for. The Chinese have now had 40+ years of
experience pushing and pulling the levers of an embryonic economy into the
behemoth it has become.
So far so good.
But the easy part is rapidly drawing
to a close. The leadership is not dumb. They know and understand the challenge
they face. Xi Jinping may be better placed than Hu Jintao was to transition
into reform mode. The difference is that Xi has thus far shown he has solid
control of his Politburo. Hu Jintao never got there and much of the current
corruption campaign is aimed at the previous members who fattened their
fortunates and lined their wallets. That is step one.
The second step, reform, is the real
challenge. How do you open up an economic system and reduce government control
of the economy and still hold onto the levers of power that a one-party
government needs to stay in power?
Here again, there is no precedent, no
playbook, no prior experience. Virgin territory again as has been the case
since modern China began to develop in the 1970s.
There is agreement (as the Rhodium
study indicates) on what needs to be done. But how?
No comments:
Post a Comment